TITLE 20. PUBLIC UTILITIES AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS
REGISTRAR'S NOTICE: The State Corporation Commission is
claiming an exemption from the Administrative Process Act in accordance with
§ 2.2-4002 A 2 of the Code of Virginia, which exempts courts,
any agency of the Supreme Court, and any agency that by the Constitution is
expressly granted any of the powers of a court of record.
Titles of Regulations: 20VAC5-200. Public Utility Accounting (repealing 20VAC5-200-10).
20VAC5-300. Energy Regulation; In General (repealing 20VAC5-300-10, 20VAC5-300-30,
20VAC5-300-50, 20VAC5-300-60, 20VAC5-300-80, 20VAC5-300-100).
20VAC5-306. Standards for Integrated Resource Planning and
Investments in Conservation and Demand Management for Natural Gas (repealing 20VAC5-306-10 through
20VAC5-306-40).
20VAC5-311. Interim Rules Governing Electric and Natural Gas
Retail Access Pilot Programs (repealing 20VAC5-311-10 through
20VAC5-311-60).
20VAC5-317. Rates for Standby Service Furnished to Certain
Renewable Cogeneration Facilities Pursuant to § 56-235.1:1 of the Code of
Virginia (repealing 20VAC5-317-40).
20VAC5-320. Regulations Governing Transfer of Transmission Assets
to Regional Transmission Entities (repealing 20VAC5-320-120).
Statutory Authority: § 12.1-13 of the Code of Virginia.
Effective Date: April 14, 2020.
Agency Contact: Andrea Macgill, Associate General Counsel, State Corporation
Commission, P.O. Box 1197, Richmond, VA 23218, telephone (804) 371-9064, FAX
(804) 371-9240, or email andrea.macgill@scc.virginia.gov.
Summary:
The amendments repeal certain obsolete regulations and schedules
that (i) have been replaced by regulations in another chapter, (ii) are
duplicative of State Corporation Commission orders or partial orders, or (iii)
require certain utilities to submit filings with the commission on or before
dates in the past.
AT RICHMOND, MARCH 6, 2020
COMMONWEALTH
OF VIRGINIA, ex rel.
STATE
CORPORATION COMMISSION
CASE NO. PUR-2019-00219
Ex
Parte: In the matter of repealing regulations
ORDER REPEALING REGULATIONS
On
January 9, 2020, the State Corporation Commission ("Commission")
issued an Order Initiating Rulemaking Proceeding in this docket for the purpose
of repealing numerous regulations adopted by the Commission pursuant to § 12.1-13
of the Code of Virginia ("Code"), as well as various statutes in
Title 56 of the Code. These regulations are codified in Title 20 of the
Virginia Administrative Code ("VAC").
The
Commission's Order Initiating Rulemaking Proceeding proposed to repeal certain
regulations on the basis that they (1) contain certain obsolete rules and
schedules that are no longer required, or (2) are duplicative of Commission
orders or partial orders and it is not necessary for such orders to be included
in the VAC. The regulations that the Commission proposed to repeal included the
following: 20 VAC 5-200-10; 20 VAC 5-300-10; 20 VAC 5-300-30; 20 VAC
5-300-50; 20 VAC 5-300-60; 20 VAC 5-300-80; 20 VAC 5-300-100; 20 VAC
5-306-10 et seq. (entire chapter); 20 VAC 5-311-10 el seq. (entire chapter); 20
VAC 5-317-40; and 20 VAC 5-320-120.
Interested
persons were given the opportunity to comment or request a hearing on the
proposed repeal of these regulations. No person filed comments, nor did anyone
request a hearing in this matter.
NOW
THE COMMISSION, upon consideration of this matter, is of the opinion and finds
that the regulations set forth in the Commission's Order Initiating Rulemaking
Proceeding in this docket should be repealed.
Accordingly,
IT IS ORDERED THAT:
(1)
The regulations appended hereto as Appendix A are hereby repealed effective
April 1,2020.
(2)
A copy of this Order and the rules repealed herein shall be provided to the
Register of Regulations for appropriate publication.
(3)
There being nothing further to come before the Commission, this case is hereby
dismissed.
AN
ATTESTED COPY hereof shall be sent by the Clerk of the Commission to: C. Meade
Browder, Jr., Senior Assistant Attorney General, Division of Consumer Counsel,
Office of the Attorney General, 202 N. 9th Street, 8th Floor, Richmond,
Virginia 23219-3424. A copy hereof shall be delivered to the Commission's
Office of General Counsel and the Divisions of Public Utility Regulation and
Utility Accounting and Finance.
20VAC5-200-10. Adoption of revised uniform system of accounts
for gas utilities. (Repealed.)
At the National Association of Regulatory
and Utilities Commissioners' (NARUC) convention held in Phoenix, Arizona, on
November 17-20, 1958, resolutions were adopted recommending to the commissions
represented by membership in the Association the adoption of revised Uniform
Systems of Accounts for Gas Utilities. This system of accounts was published
and adopted by a number of state commissions, including this Commission.
Although there have been numerous changes
in accounting principles and practices and although the Federal Power
Commission has adopted numerous amendments to the systems of accounts that it
prescribes for gas utilities, there have been no amendments to the NARUC system
since it was issued in 1958.
Realizing the need to bring the NARUC
system up-to-date, the NARUC Accounting Committee undertook a complete review
of the presently recommended system of accounts. The review of the system of
accounts has been completed by the Association's Committee on Accounts and
Statistics, and the Committee's recommended revisions have resulted in adoption
and recommendation of a new, revised system of accounts by the NARUC.
Also, this Commission is aware that the
Federal Power Commission, by order No. 490 issued on August 22, 1973, has
eliminated Account No. 271 - Contributions In Aid of Construction - and
prescribed disposition of the balance in such account and the treatment of
future contributions in aid of construction. This change was not included in
the NARUC recommended revised system of accounts.
NOW, UPON CONSIDERATION, the Commission is
of the opinion and finds:
1. That the system of accounts for gas utilities prescribed by
this Commission should be revised to conform with the recommended revisions of
the NARUC except in regard to Account No. 271. The Commission's prescribed
treatment of contributions in aid of construction should be substantially the
same as that of the Federal Power Commission;
2. That, however, the gas utilities under the jurisdiction of the
Commission should continue to maintain the amounts of contributions in aid of
construction on a memorandum basis for tax and other related purposes where
such detail is needed;
3. That implementation of the revised system of accounts for gas
utilities should become effective January 1, 1974, and the gas utilities should
implement a memorandum record of contributions in aid of construction at that
time; accordingly
IT IS ORDERED:
1. That the uniform system of accounts for gas utilities
prescribed by the Commission, effective January 1, 1961, be discontinued and
cancelled as of January 1, 1974;
2. That every gas utility company operating in this Commonwealth
shall institute and place into effect a system of accounts in accordance with
the rules and regulations set forth in the Uniform System of Accounts for Gas
Utilities, Classes A and B, C or D as applicable to it, prepared by the
Committee on Accounts and Statistics of the National Association of Regulatory
and Utilities Commissioners and filed with this order marked respectively as
"Uniform System of Accounts For Class A and B Gas Utilities,"
"Uniform System of Accounts For Class C Gas Utilities," and Uniform
System of Accounts For Class D Gas Utilities," such system of accounts to
become effective, except for Account No. 271 - Contributions in Aid of Construction;
3. That the Acting Chief Accountant to the Commission shall cause
to be prepared a written directive setting forth treatment for contributions in
aid of construction in substantial compliance with the ordering provisions of
Federal Power Commission Order No. 490 and upon approval of such directive by
the Commission, the same shall be forwarded to each gas utility and shall
replace and supersede all prescribed treatment in the NARUC recommended system
of accounts in conflict therewith; and, that the Acting Chief Accountant shall
cause to be prepared as an addendum to the written directive, an instruction
for the approval of the Commission, prescribing the memorandum record which
shall be maintained for contributions in aid of construction for tax and other
administrative purposes;
4. That effective January 1, 1974, every gas utility operating in
this Commonwealth shall commence to keep its books and records in accordance
with the system of accounts and the written directive for contributions in aid
of construction filed herein;
5. That an attested copy of this order, together with, or as soon
hereafter as available, the revised system of accounts and written directive
and addendum of the Acting Chief Accountant, shall be sent to each gas utility
operating in this Commonwealth.
20VAC5-300-10. Investigation of promotional allowances and
practices of public utilities. (Repealed.)
Opinion, BY THE COMMISSION:
This proceeding was instituted by order of
the Commission on April 12, 1966. The order instituted an investigation to
determine:
(a) What promotional allowances are offered, made or given to
anyone or what promotional practices are used or followed with respect to
anyone by the public utilities which are parties to this proceeding in
connection with the furnishing or the offer to furnish in this State of either
electric energy or gas for heat, light or power;
(b) Whether any such promotional allowances or practices are in
violation of the laws of this State; and,
(c) What action should be taken by the Commission in the public
interest with respect to any such promotional allowances or practices.
This Commission has had jurisdiction over
such matters since its creation as the governmental agency regulating public
utilities. Also, utility companies have engaged in promotional practices,
including the giving of promotional allowances and similar inducements to the
use of their service, for many years. The Commission has received no complaints
from consumers in connection with such promotional practices, and in fact no
formal complaint has ever been filed with respect to such practices except to
the extent that the testimony, arguments and briefs of the parties in this
proceeding constitute such complaints.
In the 1966 Session of the Virginia
General Assembly representatives of the fuel oil dealers were responsible for
the introduction of a bill which would have made unlawful promotional
allowances and practices of the types engaged in by many utility companies.
This legislation was not passed by the General Assembly, but in its place there
was enacted a provision directing the Commission to investigate the promotional
allowances and practices of public utilities and take such action as such
investigation may indicate to be in the public interest.
On February 7, 1966, prior to the
introduction of this bill, the Commission directed each electric and gas
utility operating within the State of Virginia to furnish to the Commission a
copy of the sales promotional programs which they had in use. This was done by
the utilities, and these promotional programs are the subject of this
proceeding.
Pursuant to the order of April 12, 1966, a
hearing on this matter was held on June 20, 21 and 22, 1966. The electric
utilities, the gas utilities and the fuel oil dealers appeared and were
represented by counsel. The electric and gas utilities presented a great deal
of frequently repetitious evidence in support of their positions. The fuel oil
dealers, however, did not offer any evidence, stating that it would only be
repetitious of that presented by the gas utilities. Opening briefs were filed
by the electric and gas utilities on September 1, 1966, and reply briefs were
filed on September 21, 1966.
At the hearing and in their briefs the
electric utilities concentrated on justifying their promotional allowances and
practices and did not concern themselves with the allowances and practices of
their competitors. Conversely, the gas utilities concentrated on challenging
the allowances and practices of the electric utilities and made no attempt to
justify their own, other than as being necessary to compete with the practices
of the electric utilities.
The basic position of the electric
utilities may be summarized generally as follows: promotional allowances and
underground wiring programs are desirable and in the public interest because
they stimulate the growth of use of electricity and this growth is necessary to
keep electric rates low; the uses of electricity which are promoted in this
fashion are uses which have high revenues in relation to costs and therefore
are desirable uses from the utility's point of view; the allowances and
underground wiring practices are not discriminatory because the benefits of
them are available to all customers who meet the objective requirements which
have been established; the size of the allowances and costs of other
promotional practices are not large enough to impose a burden on customers in
other classes and are recovered in a reasonably short period of time; and it is
in the public interest for utility management to be flexible and imaginative in
promoting increased sales of electricity. In opposition to this, the
contentions of the gas utilities may be likewise generally summarized;
promotional allowances and underground wiring programs are unjustly
discriminatory in that they confer benefits upon some customers and deny those
benefits to others within the same general classification of service; the
practices of the electric companies are in violation of their filed tariffs;
the revenues generated as a result of the challenged promotions, when all the
costs of generating those revenues are taken into account, are insufficient to
permit the electric companies to recover those costs in a reasonable time and
therefore there is discrimination against other customers; and the public
interest requires that all cash allowances and similar inducements be
prohibited and that underground electric service be furnished only upon payment
of the additional cost of such service by the person who benefits from it.
At the outset the electric utilities also
defended certain promotional programs which guaranteed to electric heating
customers that their heating bills would not exceed certain amounts or that
they would be satisfied in every respect with such electric heat, and the gas
utilities likewise opposed these programs. During the hearing the Commission,
in an interim ruling which is hereby reaffirmed1, declared that such programs
were unlawful and had to be discontinued, and the electric utilities have not
pursued this matter any further.
The principal questions to be determined
in this proceeding are whether utility promotional allowances and practices
constitute "unjust discrimination" in violation of § 56-247 of the
Code of Virginia, and what action is necessary to eliminate or prevent such
unjust discrimination.
The evidence in this proceeding,
particularly the report of Ernest M. Jordan, Jr., Assistant Engineer of the
Commission (Exhibit No. 1), shows a variety of promotional allowances and
practices by the utilities. The principal challenge (other than with respect to
those guarantees of cost and satisfaction which have already been held to be
invalid) has been to the payment of cash incentives for the installation of
certain electric appliances and to the furnishing of underground distribution
at partial or no cost to customers who make certain uses of electricity.
In general the payment of cash allowances
or incentives was not shown to be illegal or contrary to the public interest in
this case. The programs under which such payments are made do provide for
varying treatment of customers within residential, commercial and industrial
classifications. However, these classifications are not exclusive, and
reasonable subclassifications may be made. In general, the classifications made
by the electric utilities in their promotional programs are those based on the
amount and character of the consumption of electricity: Gold Medallion homes,
homes with electric heat, homes with electric water heaters, homes with certain
other electric appliances. The evidence showed that the uses of electricity
promoted tended to improve the utilization of the installed plant of the
utilities and thereby improve the annual load factor of those utilities.
Moreover, it was shown that the additional revenues generated by the uses of
electricity promoted was sufficient to enable the utilities to recover those
costs within a reasonable period of time - generally speaking, less than a year
on the basis of gross revenues and less than two years if gross revenues are
reduced by application of the system operating ratio. We believe this
effectively prevents any discrimination against other customers and actually
operates to the benefit of all the customers. The weight of decided authority
from other States is to the same effect. See, for example, Gifford v. Central
Maine Power Co., 217 A. 2d 200 (1966); Rossi v. Garton, 60 PUR 3d 210 (1965);
Re Delaware Power & Light Co., 56 PUR 3d 1(1964); Re Savannah Electric and
Power Company, 45 PUR 3d 88 (1962).
It would be against the public interest to
hamper the growth of a utility's business for the purpose of enabling an
unregulated industry to make more money. The fuel oil dealers object to letting
the utilities offer inducements to increase the consumption of their products.
But if the utilities could not attract new business their customers would have
to pay higher rates, so that the economic consequences of the fuel oil dealers'
proposal would be the same as if they were demanding that utility rates be increased
to the point where nobody could afford to heat his house with gas or
electricity. That would not be in the public interest.
In recent years the gas companies have
been taking business from the oil companies, and, still more recently, the
electric companies have been getting a small percentage of the heating
business. The gas companies find themselves in much the same predicament that
the railroads found themselves in when their former customers began to prefer
to travel by bus or plane. The principle involved is that the public interest
requires that the public be allowed to choose between competing public service
companies the service that it prefers.
Motor buses have put the trolley lines out
of business. In Petersburg, Hopewell and City Point Railway Company v.
Commonwealth, 152 Va. 193, a trolley-car line was rendering perfectly adequate
service between Petersburg and Hopewell, but the Commission nevertheless issued
a certificate to a motor bus carrier to parallel the car line. The court said (p.
202):
"The State is under no obligation to protect the car line, or
to see that its operations are financially successful."
And at page 205:
"When people generally wish to travel in this way, they
should be permitted to do so, and it is no sufficient answer to say that other
carriers, in other ways, stand ready to give the necessary service."
It is the duty of the managers of a
utility to do all they can to reduce costs. Every year the electric companies,
for example, are buying bigger and more economical generators, they are
building plants in the coal fields (which hurts the railroads), they are
developing nuclear power plants (which hurts the coal industry), they are
installing transmission lines of higher voltages, and they seek to persuade
governments to lower their taxes. When their costs are reduced the savings
inure to the benefit of the consumers in lower rates. The promotional
allowances of gas and electric companies are likewise designed to reduce unit
costs by increasing consumption.
Although the general concept of
promotional allowances for certain uses of gas or electricity is not unlawful,
several applications of it revealed by the record are. Virginia Electric and
Power Company (Vepco) gives an allowance of $20 for an electric range when it is
installed at the same time as an electric water heater (the water heater
installation brings $40) but an electric range otherwise installed entitles the
owner to no allowance. There is no rational basis for this distinction, and
therefore it is discriminatory. Vepco's gas department gives allowances for
conversion to gas from all fuels other than electricity. It is understandable
that Vepco does not wish to pay to induce an electric customer to become a gas
customer, but if it is to offer allowances for conversions to gas it must do so
uniformly and not discriminate against customers who convert from electricity.
In contrast, Washington Gas Light Company
pays up to four times as much for conversions from electricity as it does for
conversions from coal or oil. This discriminates against the consumers who
receive the smaller allowances.
Of course, any promotional allowance that
is not uniformly applied among the customers meeting its requirements is
unjustly discriminatory. Both Appalachian Power Company and Natural Gas Service
Company have adjusted bills or furnished free service in certain instances
where heat was required to dry out a newly constructed house. The record showed
other instances where incentives had been negotiated on a case-by-case basis. This
is clearly unlawful. All of these specific discriminatory allowances are hereby
disapproved.
The second major area of contention in
this proceeding has been the development by the electric companies of
underground distribution plans. These plans vary in detail considerably, but
the basic concept is that a customer or builder desiring underground service
must pay the average difference between underground and overhead construction
cost to obtain it unless the residence or development is Gold Medallion or All-Electric,
in which event all or part of the difference in actual cost will be absorbed by
the electric company.
The public is becoming more and more
interested in underground distribution of electricity, and it is in the public
interest to encourage such underground distribution. However, so long as the
cost of underground is substantially more than the cost of overhead, the
customer who receives the underground service must, in one way or another pay
for it, regardless of whether underground distribution is voluntarily chosen or
required by local ordinance. Otherwise, there would be an unjust burden on
customers who are served by the less expensive but less desirable overhead
method. There are a number of methods by which the customer can be required to pay
for underground service. It can be done through cash payment of the actual
difference in cost between underground and overhead, payment of the average
difference in cost between underground and overhead, the establishment of a
separate rate for underground electric service, the addition of an underground
surcharge to existing rates or a credit based on anticipated revenues. So long
as the method of repayment selected by the utility company is reasonable and
not unjustly discriminatory, the method should be determined by the company and
not by the Commission.
The underground distribution plans
considered in this proceeding are, in general, combinations of the
"average difference in cost plan" and the "credit for
anticipated revenue plan." However, the credit is not given on a pure
revenue basis, but rather is tied generally to the total electric concept, and
this is what the gas companies find objectionable. In the future, beginning
with the year 1967, we will require such plans to be based primarily on a pure
revenue basis.
This proceeding has revealed that whereas
most of the promotional allowances and practices of the electric and gas
utilities are lawful and nondiscriminatory, not all of them are, and it appears
that without adequate supervision in the heat of competition there is
substantial opportunity for discriminatory concessions to be made. For these
reasons we consider it to be in the public interest for the Commission to be
fully and constantly aware of the promotional allowances and practices which
the utilities have in effect in order that it may insure that none of them are
unlawfully discriminatory and that none of them are administered in an
unlawfully discriminatory way. To this end, henceforth each utility shall file
a description of its promotional allowances and practices with the Commission.
1. Each utility shall, before January 1, 1967, file with the
Commission new schedules giving in detail the terms and conditions governing
charges for underground wiring or governing construction on the customer's side
of the meter, and giving in detail all allowances of any kind. The schedules
shall define each class of customer and each charge and each allowance so
specifically as to leave no room for bargaining between the utility and the
customer. The new schedules shall be effective on and after February 1, 1967,
and shall supersede the schedules heretofore filed. Thereafter, no change in
any such schedule shall become effective until thirty days after it has been
accepted for filing by the Commission.
2. A utility may not, directly, or indirectly through a third
person, promise that a customer will be satisfied with the cost of service. If
it gives estimates of costs it must make it perfectly clear that an estimate is
an estimate and not a guaranty or warranty.
3. A utility that sells appliances can guarantee that they will
work properly and that it will take them back if they do not. It cannot
guarantee that the customer will be "satisfied" in the sense that the
customer can get his money back merely by saying that he is dissatisfied. Such
a promise would enable the customer to get his money back if the costs exceeded
the estimate and would give the estimate the force of a promise. For the same
reason a utility may not agree to reimburse in whole or in part an independent
contractor who gives a guaranty that the utility could not give.
4. Allowances against charges for underground wiring must be based
on estimated consumption and not on specified kinds of appliances used by the
consumer.
5. An allowance given to any person for installing or procuring
the installation of an appliance must be the same whether or not the appliance
is substituted for an appliance already in use. If the appliance is substituted
for an appliance already in use, the allowance must be the same regardless of
the fuel used in the appliance already in use.
6. An allowance given for the installation of two or more
appliances must be the sum of the allowances given for the installation of each
of the appliances separately.
1There is no objection to a reasonable guarantee of satisfaction
so long as it excludes satisfaction with respect to cost of the electric or gas
service.
20VAC5-300-30. Final order; implementing federal rules
concerning cogeneration and small power production facilities. (Repealed.)
Pursuant to § 210 of the Public Utility
Regulatory Policies Act of 1978 ("PURPA") (Public Law 95-617, Title
II, § 210, 92 Stat. 3144, 16 USCS § 824a-3) the Commission entered an order on
November 26, 1980, establishing the present case for the purpose of determining
appropriate rates and provisions under said section for the above listed
Virginia electric cooperatives ("Cooperatives"). By that same order,
Cooperatives were directed to file proposed rates and information relating to
the development of rates pursuant to PURPA § 210. The Commission also scheduled
a public hearing for January 20, 1981.
By order dated January 13, 1981, the
Commission allowed the Division of Consumer Counsel (Office of the Attorney
General) additional time to file its information and made similar changes for
filing protests and protestant testimony.
A public hearing was held before Charles
W. Hundley, Hearing Examiner, on January 20, 1981, in the Jefferson Building,
Richmond, Virginia. Counsel appearing were James V. Lane, for Cooperatives;
Walter A. Marston, Jr., for the Virginia Hydro Power Association
("Hydro"); Eric M. Page, for the Division of Consumer Counsel, Office
of Attorney General; and Glenn P. Richardson and A. Lynn Ivey, III, for the
Commission. Protestant Jerry S. Rosenthal appeared pro se.
One intervenor appeared at the hearing.
On March 6, 1981, the Hearing Examiner
filed his report. Subsequent to that date, the Attorney General, Jerry
Rosenthal, and Hydro filed exceptions to the report.
NOW, THE COMMISSION, having considered the
record and the applicable law FINDS:
1. That Cooperatives avoided costs based upon Cooperatives cost of
wholesale power is reasonable;
2. That each Qualifying Facility ("QF") with a capacity
exceeding 100 KW shall negotiate the terms of its sale of electricity with
Cooperative and that the Commission will stand ready to arbitrate in the event
that an agreement cannot be reached;
3. That interconnection costs, as defined by FERC Rule, 18 CFR
§ 292.101(7), should be prepaid at the time of installation or over a period of
up to three years, at the option of the QF, or over such longer period of time
as may be mutually agreeable to the parties;
4. That, in cases in which QF's pay interconnection costs over a
period of time, Cooperatives should be allowed to collect interest, the rate of
such interest not to exceed the cost of Cooperatives most recent issue of long
term debt;
5. That the record is inadequate to establish a metering charge,
however, the costs associated with the installation of additional metering may
be included as an interconnection cost;
6. That the QF should have the option of either a simultaneous
purchase-sale transaction or the sale only of its excess power; selection of
such option shall be expressed in its contract and shall be for a period of not
less than one year;
7. That Cooperatives shall revise their rates for the purpose of
power from QF's in accordance with any permanent change in wholesale power
costs;
8. That Cooperatives shall comply with the Staff proposal for the
annual filing of cogeneration information with this Commission; accordingly,
IT IS ORDERED:
1. That on or before September 1, 1981, each Cooperative shall
file revised schedules in accordance with the findings herein;
2. That each Cooperative shall file the following data with the
Commission on or before March 1 of each year, beginning March 1, 1982 (such
data shall cover the twelve months ending the previous December 31):
- The name and location of each QF interconnected with Cooperative
- The design capacity of each QF
- The amount of energy purchased from each QF
- The amount of energy sold to each QF
- Copies of any contracts entered into between Cooperative and
QF's
- Avoided cost data of the type required by 18 CFR § 292.302
3. That, there appearing nothing further to be done in this
matter, the case be dismissed from the docket and the papers placed in the file
for ended causes.
20VAC5-300-50. Natural gas industrial rates and
transportation policies. (Repealed.)
On April 4, 1986, the Commission issued an
order establishing a rulemaking proceeding to reassess natural gas industrial
rates and transportation policies in Virginia. This hearing resulted from the
changes in the natural gas industry most immediately caused by the issuance of Order
436 by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC). This Order is altering
the traditional roles of the various components of the industry - producer,
pipeline, local distribution company and end user. While the impetus and
control of much of the change remains at the federal level, the successful
operation of the FERC induced programs will be determined by the approach taken
by state commissions in the implementation on the state level.
The changes have been fueled by a number
of factors: decontrol of wellhead gas prices, the decline in oil prices, the
competition given our domestic gas industry by Mexican and Canadian gas, the
advent of the spot market and contract carriage provisions. Since 1980 the
industry has seen an excess supply of gas. This has resulted in increased risk
to producers and pipelines under the traditional marketing functions and
increased pressure by industrial users to have available a mechanism to obtain
natural gas at lower prices. Devices such as Special Marketing Programs, shifts
in the allocation of fixed costs in demand and commodity charge components of
the minimum bill, and elimination of variable costs from the minimum bill were
precursors of the present FERC attempts to enable the natural gas industry to
respond to the very real competitive forces in the marketplace.
The federal government through FERC has
determined that users of natural gas in this country will benefit if they are
given the option to purchase gas directly from the producers and have it
transported by the pipelines to their point of use. This policy dramatically
alters the traditional role of the interstate pipeline, the intrastate pipeline
and the local distribution company. This policy decision, embodied in FERC
Order 436 and now expanded in Order 451, poses substantial practical and
philosophical problems. The restructuring of this industry cannot happen
quickly and the fruits or disadvantages of this move will take even more time
to realize and evaluate.
While this shift began on the federal
level and initially involved those entities subject to the jurisdiction of
FERC, local distribution companies and intrastate pipelines as an integral part
on the industry, must also adjust to the new way of doing business. Failure to
do so clearly would frustrate national policy. As in the telecommunications
industry, it is now incumbent on the local utilities and state regulators to
make federal policies work for the public good.
In our April order, we invited interested
parties to participate in this rulemaking proceeding, directed Staff to
complete its investigation and file its analysis and report, and further,
identified several critical issues which the Commission hoped parties to the
proceeding would address and which the Commission believed needed to be addressed
to facilitate the transition of the natural gas industry in Virginia to a more
competitive environment.
As noted in the order establishing the
rulemaking proceeding, the Commission has received numerous formal as well as
informal requests for guidance and analysis of specific problems related to
industrial rate design and transportation policies. Some of the problems which
have been raised in those inquiries and proceedings can and should be most
effectively decided on a general basis to facilitate a more orderly development
of the regulatory scheme. However, although we intend to address many of the
problems, this proceeding and this order are intended to provide only a
framework for the development of the natural gas industry in Virginia. Actual rates
and company specific considerations should and will be taken into account on a
company by company basis within the framework established herein.
Beginning on June 17, 1986, the Commission
conducted public hearings to receive testimony and comments from interested
parties on the development of an appropriate rate design for industrial rates
and transportation policies in general. A number of diverse parties provided
input on the issues raised by the Commission and by the Staff report. The
Commission would like to thank all parties for their contributions in this
proceeding and their efforts to suggest a reasoned and equitable approach to
this new and still changing environment.
Appearances were entered by Edward L.
Flippen for Anheuser-Busch Companies, Inc. (Anheuser-Busch), BASF Corporation
(BASF), James River Corporation (James River), Owens-Illinois, Inc.
(Owens-Illinois), Reynolds Metals Company (Reynolds), and Westvaco Corporation
(Westvaco); Fielding L. Williams, Jr. for Celanese Smoking Products, a Division
of Celanese Corporation (Celanese); Charles F. Midkiff and Louis N. Monacell
for Allied Corporation (Allied); Anthony Gambardella for the Division of
Consumer Counsel, Office of the Attorney General (Consumer Counsel); Eric M.
Page and David B. Kearney for the City of Richmond (Richmond); Guy T. Tripp,
III and James F. Bowe, Jr. for Virginia Natural Gas (VNG); Donald R. Hayes for
Northern Virginia Natural Gas, a Division of Washington Gas Light Company
(NVNG); Wilbur L. Hazlegrove for Roanoke Gas Company (Roanoke); Stephen H.
Watts, II for Commonwealth Gas Services, Inc. (Services), Lynchburg Gas Company
(Lynchburg), Columbia Gas of Virginia, Inc. (Columbia) and Commonwealth Gas
Pipeline Corporation (Pipeline); Allan E. Roth for Columbia; John S. Graham,
III for Equitable Resources Energy Company; and Deborah V. Ellenberg for Staff.
TESTIMONY
Representatives from Anheuser-Busch, BASF,
James River, Owens-Illinois, Reynolds and Westvaco came forward to testify on
their own behalf. In addition, those industrial companies jointly supported the
testimony of Dr. Roy Shanker, an economic consultant. That group of industrial
end-users urged the Commission to recognize that competition and increased
transportation are in the public interest. They further urged the Commission to
unbundle transportation related services, develop cost of service rates for those
services and allow such rates to be downwardly flexible to the variable cost of
service. They also stated that the Commission should require Pipeline to make
its upstream Columbia Gulf transportation capacity entitlement available to its
contract demand customers upon their request. The industrial companies further
recommended that, to implement the policies developed in this proceeding,
utilities be directed to develop and file cost of service studies and to file
embedded cost of service transportation rates pursuant to those studies within
twelve months of the date of this order. Dr. Shanker testified that embedded
cost rates will eliminate most of the economic incentives for bypass. Mr.
Flippen, counsel for the six industrials, stated further that the Commission
need not address the question of bypass unless and until an actual case arises.
Finally, those parties supported the concept of flexible interruptible retail
rates and recommended the ceiling be based on the embedded cost of service and
the floor on the utility's marginal cost of service.
Celanese presented one witness who urged
the Commission to adopt flexible transportation rates within cost of service
parameters. Celanese's witness also stated that standby service for
transportation customers should be provided at carefully considered and
unbundled rates.
Allied presented one witness, John
Brickhill, who urged the Commission to encourage voluntary transportation by
taking a company's participation into account in establishing an appropriate
return on equity or by not allowing utilities to pass on to remaining customers
the fixed costs associated with lost load which could have been averted through
transportation. He also testified that the Commission should address the
problems associated with the allocation of upstream transportation capacity and
urged the Commission to look at the long term impact on end-users, not simply
at Pipeline's current cost of gas. He asserted that customers must rely on the
long term ability to transport gas, not simply transportation of spot market
purchases. Allied argued that transportation rates should be based on an embedded
cost of service design and should be downwardly flexible if retail sales rates
are downwardly flexible. It said that flexible pricing must be closely
scrutinized to prevent anti-competitive abuses. Mr. Brickhill stated that rate
design should,promote competition and fairness by application of cost causation
principles in a manner which would avoid undue rate shock. He observed that now
would be a good time to move to parity as gas costs overall are declining. The
impact therefore would be minimized.
The Consumer Counsel presented the
testimony of Mr. Steven Ruback. He stated that local distribution companies
(LDCs) should lower their system average cost of gas and that the Commission
should concentrate on reviewing the utility companies' purchasing practices.
With regard to rate design, the Consumer Counsel recommended rates be based on
the same non-gas margin contribution as if the customer had purchased gas from
the LDC under a non-flexible rate schedule. This, he argued, would make both
customers and utility companies indifferent as to whether a customer transports
or purchases gas from the utility. Mr. Ruback stated that such a margin
approach would avoid price signals which encouraged a customer to switch to
transportation and thereby make a lower contribution to a utility's fixed
costs. He further urged that interruptible flexible retail rates be addressed
on a company specific basis and that the floor should be based on the highest
commodity cost of gas. Further, the Consumer Counsel cautioned the Commission
against making spot market purchase dedications to particular customers and
stated that such inappropriate dedications would result in unjust and
preferential rates.
Richmond presented the testimony of one
witness, Michael Moore. Mr. Moore agreed with most other parties that increased
competition and transportation are in the public interest. Mr. Moore also urged
the Commission to address the allocation of upstream capacity and stated that
customers must have the assurance that upstream capacity will be available or
there will be a resulting disincentive to transportation. Moreover, he stated
that such allocation should be available to Pipeline's customers since they pay
the contract demand costs to reserve the capacity.
Virginia Natural Gas, through its witness,
Ann Rasnic, also urged the Commission to find as a matter of policy that
transportation is in the public interest. It also urged the Commission to
consider allocation of upstream capacity and argued that the customers of
Pipeline need the assurance that transportation will be available through that
upstream capacity to facilitate economic and reliable service to the end-user.
VNG supported staff's recommendation that transportation rates be designed on
an embedded cost of service basis, with some contribution to contract demand
costs included in interruptible rates. Ms. Rasnic urged the Commission to
retain interruptible flexible retail rates within specific parameters. She
recommended the floor be based on a utility's weighted average commodity cost
of gas (WACCOG) unless the utility can show that something less than that
WACCOG is necessary to compete with alternate fuels and still provides a net
benefit to the firm customer. VNG also recommended that the ceiling of the
authorized range should be the firm industrial sales rate. Finally, VNG
suggested the Commission support the general concept of an incentive proposal
which would encourage a utility company to maximize throughput from
interruptible sales and transportation volumes. Under the mechanism, any
shortcomings or additional revenue generated over a target level would be
shared between stockholders and ratepayers according to the risk borne by each.
VNG stated that the proposal is in the public interest because it reduces the
need for base rate changes by eliminating severe shifts in utility earnings and
further, it provides an incentive to increase throughput resulting from
interruptible sales and transportation volumes which, of course, is in the
public interest of all parties.
Northern Virginia Natural Gas (NVNG) also
participated in the rulemaking proceeding and presented two witnesses, Jack
Keane and Frank Hollewa. NVNG stated that, as a general matter, the transition
from a regulated environment to a market driven environment will impact each
local LDC differently according to each company's size and load profile;
accordingly, it recommended that this rule-making should only present broad
guidelines to provide flexibility for company operations. Moreover, NVNG
supported a gradual phasing out of the industrial subsidy of firm rates. In
addition, transportation, the company asserted, should be voluntary or with
some provision for waiver or exemption and should only be offered on a
interruptible basis until more experience is gained with the service. It also
recommended the establishment of minimum criteria, by each LDC, relating to
size, delivery point, and contract term. Transportation rates, NVNG stated,
should be flexible and market driven. NVNG said interruptible flexible retail rates
should be established within a floor based on an LDC's WACCOG and each LDC
should be allowed to dedicate a specific package of spot market gas to an
industrial customer.
Roanoke did not introduce the testimony of
any witnesses; however, its attorney, Wilbur Hazlegrove stated the company's
position. As a general policy matter, he stated that the LDC was charged with
protecting the firm residential customers and that there was no obligation to
serve industrial customers. He was doubtful that the Commission would be able
to handle a transition to a market driven environment smoothly and cautioned
the Commission to proceed slowly, concentrating on more pressing problems, such
as the take-or-pay costs issue before FERC. He stated that there was no need to
mandate transportation, as the industry was already responding to the
competitive market. He called transportation effectively a bypass of the
utility system supply and stated that the traditional distributor monopoly of
gas supply would soon be replaced by "a proliferation of purchasers
chasing an inadequate gas supply with big bucks." Industrial rates and
transportation policies, he urged, should be developed on a company specific
basis.
Pipeline, Columbia, Services and Lynchburg
presented their comments through their counsel, Stephen H. Watts, II. By its
statement of position on future allocation of upstream pipeline capacity dated
June 24, 1986, Pipeline stated that it has voluntarily allocated its upstream
transportation capacity among its five contract demand customers pursuant to
mutual agreement. It recognized the customer's need to be able to rely on such
an allocation to make longer term gas purchase commitments and stated that it
would not revoke the upstream allocation provided to its customers without
thirty days notice. Pipeline stated that the issue relative to the allocation
of upstream capacity must be decided in terms of a utility company's public
service obligation to use its available resources to offer reliable supply at
lower cost for all of the customers. However, it requested Commission guidance
on the allocation question.
Pipeline was also concerned that any
policy decisions rendered in this proceeding should not displace the
stipulation filed by several parties in Pipeline's recently concluded rate
case.1 In that case Pipeline had proposed cost based transportation rates
within and outside of contract demand (CD), provided a methodology for sharing
capacity between CD customers and provided equal priority for transportation
and sales gas volumes within firm and interruptible classifications. Pipeline
expressed concern with the impact of transportation in the long run since the
current market instability is due to temporary and extraordinary conditions.
Pipeline also urged the Commission to address the bypass question.
On behalf of Columbia, Mr. Watts stated
transportation rates ideally should be based on the non-gas sales rate schedule
margin, since there is not a significant difference between the non-gas cost of
providing transportation service and the cost of delivering gas for sale to its
customers. However, under conditions where the price is being set by the
market, he stated fixed transportation rates will result in a loss of
throughput and accordingly, Columbia recommended flexible transportation rates.
Services agreed that industrial
transportation rates should be fully allocated and distributed according to
class cost of service studies with class rates of return moving towards parity.
Services also urged that industrial rates be downwardly flexible with a floor
based on a utility's variable cost of gas sold to the industrial customer.
Transportation rates, it urged, should be the non-gas component of the
applicable sales rates and should be downwardly flexible to allow competition and
prevent bypass.
Lynchburg urged the Commission to consider
and maintain flexibility in any policy or framework adopted in this proceeding
to allow LDC's to compete with nonregulated markets. Lynchburg also stated that
there was not a need for the Commission to mandate transportation. Lynchburg
itself offers firm and interruptible transportation but has not had a request
for either type of service.
Mr. Cody Walker appeared on behalf of the
staff. He indicated that a mandatory carriage policy was not necessary but
incentives should be developed to encourage voluntary participation.
Staff recommended value of service rates
be retained for retail interruptible sales. Mr. Walker stated that the
parameters between which flexible rates could vary on a month to month basis
should be based on cost of service considerations. The fluctuation of the rate
within the established range could vary as necessary to compete with
competitive alternative fuel prices. staff recommended that the floor of the
flexible rate range be equal to a utility company's highest commodity cost of
gas plus adjustments for taxes and unaccounted for gas, unless the utility
shows that a lower floor is necessary to compete with alternate fuels and
further, that a lower floor still provides a net benefit to the firm customers.
Mr. Walker supported a ceiling based on the same rate of return as provided by
the firm industrial rates.
Staff recommended that transportation
rates be designed on an embedded cost of service basis. Incorporated into that
recommendation, staff included a contribution to compensate firm customers for
the interruptible customer's use of excess capacity because it is reasonable to
allocate some of the demand costs to interruptible customers as rent or
compensation for use of the facilities. Staff did not support flexible
transportation rates.
TRANSPORTATION POLICY
The increase in competition in the natural
gas industry has clearly been in the public interest. Competition at the
wellhead has already served to lower gas costs overall and nondiscriminatory
transportation has stimulated that competition. Even nonparticipating customers
benefit from transportation due to the increased pressures on utility companies
to lower gas costs overall to more effectively compete. Moreover, a company
which effectively competes can increase the throughput on its system and again
lower costs for all its customers. In addition, transportation provides one
more market option which a utility can offer its customers and consequently
maximizes the requisite flexibility necessary to compete with a variety of
alternatives. We agree with the majority of the parties to this proceeding that
transportation of natural gas is in the public interest. However, it is not
necessary to mandate that all utility companies file transportation tariffs and
provide that carriage. As many parties observed, as a practical matter, most
Virginia utility companies who have a demand for transportation on their
systems have effective transportation tariffs on file with this Commission.
Although we will not mandate transportation, we intend to encourage voluntary
participation in transportation programs. This Commission will review
individual company practices in future rate cases to assure that each company
maximizes utilization of its system. Several means to encourage transportation
were suggested by several parties in this proceeding. We will be critical in
the event load is lost as a result of a company's failure to transport. Such
loss will be taken into account in setting rates. Appropriate measures will
necessarily be taken into account in each company's rate case to preclude
penalizing a company who has no demand for transportation for its failure to
provide transportation.
INTERRUPTIBLE RETAIL RATES
This Commission has historically embraced
the flexible rate as a viable mechanism to provide utility companies with the
flexibility necessary to compete with unregulated alternate fuels. In January
of 1984, the Commission first approved a flexible rate for Washington Gas Light
Company.2 In the final order issued in that case we stated that:
We are confident that a flexible rate is
required in order for the Company to remain in the competitive market of
interruptible customers. If the Company were to lose its entire interruptible
load, there would be an automatic shifting of significant non-gas costs to all
firm customers. Hence, the economic viability of the Company hinges upon its
ability to generate revenues from interruptible customers, and to do so it must
have a flexible pricing structure to compete in that market.
That principle has been restated in
numerous proceedings addressing flexible rates. As the gas industry moves
toward a more competitive market it is even more essential that utility
companies retain the flexibility available through measures such as flexible
rates to be able to respond to the marketplace.
Although most parties to this proceeding
generally supported the basic concept of a flexible rate, the suggested
parameters of that mechanism varied. VNG suggested that it was more appropriate
to establish the floor based on a company's weighted average commodity cost of
gas (WACCOG) plus appropriate adjustments. Further,
VNG suggested that the ceiling be equal to
the large volume firm sales rate, rather than simply incorporating the return
included in the firm rate as suggested by staff. In addition, several parties
recommended establishing a floor based on the utility company's spot market
purchases or, in other words, to allow utilities to dedicate their cheapest
purchases to the most elastic customers.
Several parties also cautioned that each
utility company's situation will be different and will depend in part upon load
profiles and purchasing practices. Accordingly, those parties recommended that
flexible rates should be reviewed on a company specific basis.
Although we agree that specific provisions
may vary based on an individual company's market and operating characteristics,
basic guidelines can be established to provide a uniform approach to companies'
flexible rates. We conclude that the floor of a flexible rate should be based
on the highest commodity cost of gas or if more than one supplier furnishes
gas, the floor should be the weighted average commodity cost of gas. If, and we
emphasize "if," the utility can demonstrate that a lower cost is
necessary to compete with alternate fuels and further, that the firm or core
customer still receives a net benefit from retaining the interruptible sale,
the lower price will be accepted.
As pointed out by several parties, the
point at which the price necessary to retain an interruptible sale no longer
provides a benefit to the system will vary significantly from company to
company. Accordingly, it is reasonable to establish the starting point for the
floor at the highest commodity cost and allow companies to offer proof that
something less is necessary and still beneficial on a case by case basis. That
test will of course reflect an analysis of several factors, foremost of which
will be the incremental cost of gas acquired to serve the interruptible load.
To facilitate a direct comparison it may be appropriate to assume the benefits
of retaining the interruptible load will coincide with the immediate impact on
gas costs.
We will necessarily be cautious about
allowing companies to dedicate spot market purchases to the most elastic
customers. The Commission must be particularly sensitive to the protection of
the inelastic core customers. A rate design which results in inelastic
customers subsidizing the elastic customer is clearly improper. Economic
purchases should not be made solely for elastic customers to the exclusion of
purchases for system supply. The authority to make such a dedication to the
most elastic customers would also eliminate one incentive for a company to minimize
its general system costs. With a low price necessary to compete with alternate
fuels in the current market, a captive customer, or one with no ready
alternative, might be assessed the higher cost of gas without close regulatory
scrutiny. We caution all utility companies to review their general system
purchasing practices and to fulfill the statutory obligation to provide
reliable utility service at a just and reasonable cost.
The customer charge component of the rate
should reflect the fully distributed costs of providing the interruptible
service. We will closely review this in rate filings.
Finally, at this point in the evolving
competition in the gas industry, we concur with the recommendations of most
parties that it is prudent to move gradually toward parity of return in firm
industrial rates. Such movement must be gradual to minimize rate shock to
residential customers and carefully evaluated at each step.
TRANSPORTATION RATE DESIGN
A number of parties recommended the
embedded cost of service rate proposed by staff to be established as a maximum
transportation rate and that the utility companies be afforded the flexibility
to adjust the transportation rate downward from that embedded cost of service
level to the marginal cost of providing transportation service. There are
problems, however, associated with flexible transportation rates. The value of
transportation to individual customers will vary on the basis of a number of
different factors. Unlike the flexible retail rates, there is not a readily identifiable
alternate source of competition to transportation. Transportation may occur due
to any one of a number of factors ranging from wellhead cost of gas to
alternate fuel prices. To respond to these variables, the utility would need to
apply a different rate for each customer and would consequently engage in
discriminatory ratemaking between similarly situated transportation customers.
Such a framework would also result in problems with effective regulatory review
problems.
The Consumer Counsel recommended a
different approach to the design of transportation rates. Its witness, Mr.
Ruback, recommended basing transportation rates on the non-gas margin of the
applicable retail sales rate which would otherwise be available to that
customer. He stated the benefit of this rate design approach would be the
utility's revenue neutrality relative to a customer's election to transport its
own gas or purchase from the utility. At the public hearing, the Consumer
Counsel further clarified that its margin approach should be limited to
nonflexible rate schedule margins.
Other parties observed that such a margin
approach could be a goal if industrial retail rates were already based on
cost-causation principles, however, based on current rate designs, the
nonflexible margin approach results in unworkable and uncompetitive rates. Such
an approach would effectively eliminate transportation as a service option in
Virginia, thereby compounding the current problems with competitive fuel
prices. In addition, the Consumer Counsel's limitation on the margin approach
to nonflexible rates would not result in the company's operations being revenue
neutral. An alternate fuel user who could purchase gas under an interruptible
flexible rate schedule would not be purchasing gas under the firm large volume
rate schedule as its alternative to transportation service and accordingly, its
choice between a flexible sales or transportation service would not result in a
revenue neutral situation. If the limitation to nonflexible rate schedules were
removed and transportation rates were based on the appropriate margin, a wide
range of rate levels would be charged to transportation customers despite the
fact that the customers were all receiving the same type of service.
We will direct that an embedded cost of
service approach to transportation rate design be applied on a company by
company basis for both firm and interruptible transportation service. Over
time, the non-gas margin of the industrial sales rates will be more closely
aligned with the transportation rates, however at the present time we must
provide viable competitive options for utilities to offer their customers.
Moreover, since the growth in transportation service is a recent phenomenon,
development of embedded cost of service transportation rates at the present
time will not result in rate shock to the captive customers. An immediate
elimination of the subsidy currently being provided by industrial customers in
the retail rates would, however, result in rate shock. We would note, however,
that, with the recent drop in oil prices, the impetus to shift much of the
fixed costs of the utility to firm customers is already in place.
An interruptible customer does not
contribute to the fixed cost of capacity associated with peak demand and such
service is inferior to firm service, since it is interrupted during periods of
peak load; however, the interruptible service is provided through the same
facilities as firm service. Therefore there should be some compensation by the
interruptible customer to the firm customer for the use of that excess
capacity. The contribution will vary from company to company, again depending
on the customer mix and load profile, and therefore should be specifically
addressed on a company by company basis. The demand allocation applied in each
case should reflect the operating characteristics of the company.
To facilitate and expedite implementation
of the framework established herein, all gas utility companies should conduct
class cost of service studies and file them with the Commission within the next
12 months. Exemptions from this filing requirement, upon proper petition, may
be considered for small gas utilities with limited industrial loads and who
have not received requests for transportation service. Any tariffs filed should
be based on cost of service studies. Those companies who do not intend to file
rate cases in the next 12 months, should file limited applications to revise
their transportation rates where transportation is being offered in accordance
with the findings herein within that same 12 month time period.
UNBUNDLED SERVICES
There was overwhelming support for an
approach to rate design which identifies the several services which a utility
provides and separately determines the fully allocated costs of providing each
service. Unbundling services in this way provides a menu from which a customer
can tailor the type of service and degree of reliability appropriate for that
customer. The extent to which unbundling occurs will again vary from company to
company and accordingly should be evaluated on that basis, however, it provides
a reasonable approach to rate design at a time when the industry is becoming
more competitive in the services offered. Transportation and standby retail
service are two examples of services which can be easily unbundled from the
traditional retail sale and provided on an individual basis.
ALLOCATION OF UPSTREAM TRANSPORTATION
CAPACITY
One of the foremost concerns raised in
this proceeding relates to the proper allocation of upstream transportation
capacity. At the present time few interstate pipeline companies have agreed to
become open access transporters. Columbia Gas Transmission Corporation, a
primary interstate supplier for Virginia, and Columbia Gulf are, however, open
access transporters. Because they represent a major supplier for the east
coast, tremendous demand has been placed on them for transportation. This has
resulted in demand exceeding capacity available and raised serious questions
concerning the allocation of transportation capacity on their pipeline
facilities.
The FERC recently addressed the problems
with allocation of Columbia Gulf's main line capacity. The FERC defined the
"first-come/first-served" methodology which was first described in
FERC Order No. 436. The FERC has generally outlined the allocation of
transportation capacity to Columbia Gulf's wholesale customers, both for its
customers' system supply and for the wholesale customers' end-users through
March 31, 1987. The FERC directed that in making monthly nominations, the
wholesale customers should include any requests for service by their customers.
While addressing the Gulf capacity allocation generally, the FERC by Order
Approving a Settlement Offer with modifications in FERC Docket No. RP86-14-004
dated March 28, 1986, stated at page 19 that "the relationships between
Columbia Gas' wholesale customers and the end-users they serve is properly a
matter of local concern, to be determined by each customer with its end-users
and is subject to state regulatory agency oversight and/or regulation."3
Commonwealth Gas Pipeline as a direct customer of Columbia has received an
allocation of Gulf capacity pursuant to this settlement. Initially, Pipeline
used its allocated capacity to purchase spot gas for its system supply, thereby
lowering the per unit cost of gas to all customers equally. Pipeline was
informed that this arrangement did not comply with the terms of the PGA
settlement with FERC. As result Pipeline released its capacity to its direct
customers who in turn agreed to an allocation formula. Pipeline has five direct
customers - Virginia Natural Gas, Suffolk Gas, the City of Richmond, Allied and
Commonwealth Gas Services. Presently, Pipeline is operating on a shared
allocation basis; however, the stated policy of the company continues the
ability to revoke the shared allocation on thirty days notice.
Pipeline and its customers have asked for
Commission guidance on the proper allocation of Pipeline's entitlement to
upstream transportation capacity. Although the problem will be somewhat
relieved in the event that other interstate pipelines serving Virginia become
open access transporters, the problem clearly must be addressed now at least
for the short term period.
Many parties urged the Commission to
provide some assurance on the availability of upstream capacity. They are
interested in acquiring supply for the longer term, not solely from short term
spot market purchases. To do this they need more than thirty days assurance of
transportation. Moreover, they argue that Pipeline's customers pay the contract
demand associated with reserving capacity upstream and, accordingly, should be
able to elect to use that capacity or to ask Pipeline to use the capacity to
minimize its commodity cost of gas. In making that decision, those customers of
course would weigh their own ability to purchase gas at economic prices
relative to the price of their supplier.
The Commission recognizes that if gas
transportation is to work effectively and efficiently, those who wish to transport
gas must have some assurance that the capacity to transport will be available.
Without that assurance, these users are forced to purchase system supply or
leave the system for alternate fuels. All of Pipeline's LDC customers have
indicated that obligation can be best fulfilled by passing the upstream
allocation on to them. Accordingly, the choice should be Pipeline's customers.
We will monitor this situation as other interstate pipelines become open access
transporters and understand that the time may come when such allocation may be
unnecessary, impracticable or impossible. Although not bound by the FERC
settlement, we encourage local distribution companies to utilize policies which
afford a degree of reliability for transportation capacity usable by their
transportation customers.
BYPASS
The issue of bypass was also identified in
this proceeding. We define bypass to mean direct connection by an end user to
an interstate or intrastate pipeline, thereby bypassing the certificated local
distribution company. This issue involves the economic incentives for bypass as
well as its legality under present law. The Commission believes that
appropriately designed embedded cost of service rates should eliminate the
economic incentives for bypass. This will of course require the good faith
efforts of both the customer and the utility. In any event, the Commission does
not believe the record before us is adequate to resolve the legal issue at this
time.
STANDBY SERVICE
The industrial companies represented in
this proceeding generally agreed that they should bear the risk of their
election to transport gas for themselves rather than rely upon their
traditional local distribution company. Clearly, if a customer elects
transportation and should not also elect a standby service, the utility company
does not have a continuing public service obligation to sell gas to that
customer. By placing the responsibility where it belongs, on the customer to
elect what type of service it wants to take, the gas company can retain some
predictability in its requirements, a predictability which is necessary for it
to make its own system plans. Standby service should be offered at compensatory
rates.
OTHER TERMS AND CONDITIONS
Any investments made to specifically serve
a new transportation customer should be recovered from that customer;
accordingly each utility company should provide some type of guarantee through
customer charges, minimal purchase requirements, minimal monthly payments,
contract terms or some other means to assure recovery of the investment from
the specific customer.
We recognize that there are some
circumstances in which penalties may be necessary to prevent gross abuses of
system availability and to prevent large or disparate operating practices.
Penalties should not be designed to be onerous and a disincentive to
transportation, but rather should be compensatory for any additional cost which
may result from the operating problems. Application of penalties should be
addressed by each company on a company specific basis.
Adjustments for unaccounted for gas should
be made to account for any difference in deliveries where such differences can
be practically identified, for example deliveries through temperature
compensated meters vs. non-temperature compensated meters.
We have concern over tariff conditions
imposing minimum terms or volumes and other conditions which may be contrary to
the market. We will closely review the reasonableness of terms and conditions
which may be included in company tariffs.
In conclusion, we want to commend all
participants in this proceeding. This is an uncharted course for the industry,
consumers and regulators. Proposals other than those adopted herein have been
offered. We are confident the changing nature of this industry will give rise
to even more approaches to these issues generally and as they relate to a
specific company. It is essential that dialogue continue examining the broader
policy questions as well as specific rate designs and the performance of the
market and industry. We must be aware of all reasonable options to maintain our
ability to provide effective and innovative regulation which will allow us to
meet the goal of reliable gas service at a reasonable price for the public
good.
NOW, THE COMMISSION, having considered the
record and the recommendations of the parties is of the opinion and finds:
1. That increased competition and transportation are in the public
interest and the voluntary participation in transportation programs should be
encouraged;
2. That interruptible flexible rate mechanisms are reasonable and
should be retained. The parameters should reflect a floor and ceiling
consistent with the discussion above;
3. That interruptible rates should include a customer charge which
recovers the fully distributed cost associated with that service;
4. That firm industrial rates should be developed to move
gradually towards the fully distributed costs of service;
5 That transportation rates should be based on the fully
distributed costs as recommended by staff;
6. That all gas utility companies should conduct cost of service
studies to facilitate implementation of the policies established herein and
file them within the next 12 months;
7. That the rate design goals and terms and conditions of
transportation service discussed herein shall be applied to gas companies in
future rate cases;
8. That services should be unbundled to the extent practicable.
Standby service at compensatory rates should be made available to all
customers. However, those customers not electing such standby service bear the
risk associated with the decision to rely on transportation gas; and
9. That the terms and conditions of transportation service should
be developed consistent with the discussion herein. Accordingly,
IT IS ORDERED:
1. The findings and policies discussed and established herein
shall be applied in rate cases or limited issue applications filed by gas
companies subsequent to the date of this order; and
2. There appearing nothing further to be done in this proceeding,
this docket shall be closed and the papers placed in the file for ended causes.
1By Final Order dated July 11, 1986, the Commission did not adopt
the Stipulation in its entirety. Case No. PUE850052, Application of
Commonwealth Gas Pipeline Corporation, to revise its tariffs - Appeal to the
Supreme Court pending.
2Application of Washington Gas Light Company for a change in its
gas interruptible rate and other tariff provisions, 1984 SCC Report 395.
3We note that the FERC allocation order is effective only through
March of 1987, at which time it will likely be reevaluated.
20VAC5-300-60. Order adopting policy statement for recovery of
costs associated with take-or-pay liability. (Repealed.)
On August 7, 1987, the Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission ("FERC") entered Order No. 500 in its attempt
to mitigate the effects of take-or-pay liability.1 In that
Order, FERC announced its adoption, on an interim basis, of two pass-through
mechanisms to spread the liability associated with take- or-pay contracts
throughout all segments of the gas industry. As we noted in our July 6, 1988
Order for Notice and Comment, as a result of FERC's action, large amounts of
take-or-pay liability are being or have been authorized to be passed from
interstate gas pipelines to downstream gas utilities, including those in
Virginia. Some Virginia gas utilities are currently passing take-or-pay related
costs through their purchase gas adjustment ("PGA") clauses to their
customers. Because of the potential impact these costs may have on Virginia gas
utilities and their ratepayers, we have initiated the instant docket to consider
adoption of a policy which will provide for the opportunity to recover these
costs in the most equitable and efficient manner possible. We considered the
following policies:
(1) Automatic recovery of take-or-pay costs in the same manner
that contract demand charges are recovered through utility purchase gas
adjustment clauses (hereafter policy option 1);
(2) Allocation of costs associated with fixed surcharges to both
firm and interruptible gas commodity costs (hereafter policy option 2);
(3) Recovery of take-or-pay fixed surcharges on the basis of
estimated gas transportation volumes and commodity sales. If this approach were
adopted, a utility would be permitted an opportunity to recover the costs
associated with fixed take-or-pay surcharges during a defined time period. The
opportunity to recover these costs would be the same as the opportunity to
recover any other costs during the specified period. A formula could be
developed to determine the acceptable estimates of throughput, including known
and definite load losses, customer growth, normal weather, and the utility's
ability to compete. The take-or-pay fixed surcharges would terminate at the end
of the specified time period (hereafter, policy option 3).
(4) Allocation of take-or-pay liability on the basis of customer
purchase deficiencies. This policy alternative would use a base purchase period
against which recent sales purchases could be compared. Costs associated with
fixed take-or-pay surcharges could be apportioned in relation to the decreases
in sales volumes purchased by gas customers. This policy alternative resembles
the Order No. 500 allocation mechanism employed by FERC (hereafter policy
option 4).
In our July 6th Order, the Commission
invited interested parties, including the staff and jurisdictional gas
companies, to file written comments addressing the factual or legal issues
related to the four policy alternatives described above. In addition,
interested parties were given the opportunity to request oral argument.
In response to that invitation, 22 parties
filed comments, and nine requested oral argument. Parties filing comments
included: Southwestern Virginia Gas Company ("Southwestern"), United
Cities Gas Company ("United"), James River Corporation ("James
River"), General Electric Company ("GE"), Commonwealth Gas
Pipeline Corporation ("Pipeline"), Columbia Gas of Virginia
("Columbia"), Lynchburg Gas Company ("Lynchburg"), Northern
Virginia Natural Gas and Shenandoah Gas Company ("WGL Companies"),
the City of Richmond ("City"), Hadson Gas Systems, Inc.
("Hadson"), Westvaco Corporation ("Westvaco"),
Anheuser-Busch Companies et als. (Anheuser-Busch), Virginia Industrial Gas
Users ("Industrial Users"), Virginia Natural Gas, Inc.,
("VNG"), Suffolk Gas Company ("Suffolk"), Allied-Signal,
Inc. ("Allied"), Commonwealth Gas Services, Inc.
("Services"), and Roanoke Gas Company ("Roanoke"). The
Commission's staff ("staff") also filed comments. The Division of
Consumer Counsel did not participate in this proceeding. On July 20, 1988, we
issued an order reserving the afternoon of July 29, 1988, for oral argument.
I. SUMMARY OF COMMENTS AND ARGUMENT.
Many of the local gas distribution
companies, Pipeline, and industrial customers served by both LDCs and Pipeline
supported policy option 1, i.e., recovery of take-or-pay related fixed
surcharges through the demand portion of the PGA, in their comments.
Commentators supporting option 1 or a variation thereof included Pipeline,
Lynchburg, Columbia, WGL, Westvaco, Anheuser-Busch, Cos., Inc., Celanese
Fibers, Inc., Owens- Illinois Company, IBM, Allied, and VNG. Advocates of this
policy alternative generally argued that since the customers, not the utility,
received the benefits of lower wholesale costs of natural gas through the PGA,
it was appropriate for these customers to now receive take-or- pay costs
through the PGA as offsets to the earlier savings.
Several of the gas utilities supporting
option 1 argued that the Commission could not adopt any policy that
purposefully disallowed recovery of take-or-pay costs by means of an allocation
scheme which would not permit recovery of these costs, nor could it disallow
these costs absent a showing that they were imprudently incurred. These
companies stated that any disallowance of these costs would, absent a showing of
imprudence, violate the filed rate doctrine. Nantahala Power & Light Co. v.
Thornburg, 76 U.S. 953 (1986). Appalachian Power Co. v. Public Service Comm'n
of West Va., 812 F.2d 898 (4th Cir. 1987). They asserted that these cases held
that the Commission could not find that federally-mandated take-or-pay costs
were imprudently incurred by Virginia utilities as a group or individually in
the context of this proceeding. Indeed one commentator suggested that these
cases could be read as preempting the Commission from disallowing Pipeline's
recovery of Order No. 500 take-or-pay demand charges. Pipeline's Comments at
25.
Commentators supporting option 1 did so
because they found it to be administratively convenient and because it assured
complete cost recovery. In addition, many of the industrial end users favoring
PGA treatment for take-or-pay dollars depend upon transportation of spot
purchases or interruptible sales service to satisfy the bulk of their gas
supply needs. End users receiving such services are generally not subject to
the PGA of the gas utilities serving them for those services.
Many of these same commentators took the
position that the second and third policy options would not allow gas utilities
to compete with alternate fuels since addition of associated surcharges would
render gas service noncompetitive with the prices of these fuels. Several
parties further urged the Commission to reject the cumulative deficiency
approach as a form of illegal retroactive ratemaking, and as difficult to
administer, given the diverse and changing customer population of LDCs.
Some of the commentators supported options
other than PGA recovery or modifications of PGA recovery. For example, United
Cities supported recovery of take-or-pay costs on a volumetric throughput basis
to be applied to all sales and transportation services. In support of this
option, United Cities noted that it would recover costs from the broadest
possible base of customers.
Columbia and Lynchburg's joint comments
urged that recovery of the fixed surcharges should reflect the distinct nature
of the costs. They maintained that reformation costs, which are essentially
forward-looking, should be charged through the PGA to both firm and
interruptible sales customers. However, because past take-or-pay liabilities
represent transitional costs, Lynchburg and Columbia submitted that these costs
should be shared between sales and transportation classes on a volumetric
basis. During oral argument, these parties stated that if the Commission did
not wish to consider any modification of the four policy options under
consideration, they would support policy option 3.
The City of Richmond's comments focused
upon the appropriate allocation policy for Pipeline. The City urged the
Commission to implement option 4 and require Pipeline to allocate costs on the
same basis those costs were incurred. Such a sales deficiency approach, in the
City's opinion, would be fair, provide appropriate economic signals, and create
stability for future take-or-pay cost decisions.
While the Industrial Users' comments
recommended that the Commission should permit recovery of take-or-pay costs in
the same manner that contract demand charges were recovered through PGA
clauses, they also noted that the Commission should find a way for Virginia gas
utility shareholders to bear a portion of the costs associated with
take-or-pay. The Industrial Users stated that the Commission should recognize
the need for flexibility among Virginia utilities to take account of their
differing circumstances.
Joint comments filed by VNG and Suffolk
joined other Pipeline customers to emphasize the uniqueness of Pipeline's
treatment from that of LDCs. They then urged the Commission to employ the
purchase deficiency methodology used by the FERC in Order No. 500 to allocate
take-or-pay costs among Pipeline's customers but not to use such an approach
for LDCs. VNG and Suffolk stated that the cumulative deficiency methodology
matched the purchase patterns that resulted in the cost allocation to Pipeline
to the customers engaging in such purchasing practices. Finally, VNG and
Suffolk urged the Commission to adopt policy option 3 only if:
1. All ceilings were eliminated on interruptible rates to enable
LDCs to take full advantage of the market opportunities to recover take-or-pay
costs;
2. The Commission also authorized flexible take-or-pay surcharges
to enable LDCs to respond to the market;
3. The Commission allowed LDCs with a margin sharing feature to
collect take-or-pay costs prior to any sharing of margin with firm customers;
and
4. The fixed amortization periods were eliminated to recognize the
variable nature of the price differential between gas prices and prices of
competing fuels.
Services' comments observed that all four
of the policy options under consideration were flawed. Of the four, Services
noted that it supported policy option 3 if the amortization period was flexible
to allow full recovery of take-or- pay costs. Services supported this approach
because it believed that take-or-pay costs were incurred to serve all markets
and customers of Services and other LDCs or provide a more market oriented
industry, thereby benefitting both sales and transportation customers alike.
Therefore, it believed that all of its sales and transportation customers
should pay these costs.
Services criticized option 1, PGA flow
through of these surcharges, as placing too much of a burden on firm sales
customers. Services noted that ". . . the filed tariffs of Services [did]
not break tariff rates into demand and commodity components. All costs [were]
rolled into the weighted average cost of gas, making determination of contract
demand charges difficult." Services' Comments at 23.
Services found policy option 2
unacceptable because it could force interruptible sales customers to transportation
or completely off-line as they converted to alternative fuel. It characterized
policy option 4 as unworkable. Services noted that it would be nearly
impossible for it to make determinations regarding customer purchase
deficiencies for over 62,000 retail customers. Due to a constantly changing
customer base, Services asserted that adoption of policy option 4 would leave
unanswered questions such as how to treat customers who no longer have gas
service, modify the type of service they receive, or join the system as new
customers.
Roanoke also submitted comments. In its
comments, it urged the Commission to join Virginia LDCs in their participation
in FERC proceedings involving interstate pipelines and to encourage LDCs to
develop and implement initiatives for the passthrough of take-or-pay surcharges
finally approved. In addition, Roanoke supported a variation of policy options
1 and 3.
Roanoke urged the Commission to adopt
policies permitting it to amortize the recovery of take-or-pay costs from firm
service customers over a 60 month period, together with interest, at the same
rates from time to time allowed on customer deposits and refunds. Roanoke also
suggested that firm customers be credited with periodic surcharge collections
from interruptible sales customers during a five year amortization period under
a special incremental surcharge tariff designed to recover from interruptible
sales the difference between the PGA adjusted commodity sales rate and as much
as the equivalent value of No. 2 fuel oil. Roanoke stated that the foregoing
mechanism would permit it to recover fixed and volumetric surcharges related to
take-or-pay liability in the same manner that contract demand charges are
recovered under Roanoke's PGA. In this way, Roanoke believed it could recover a
portion of its take-or-pay costs from industrial customers, who, in Roanoke's
opinion, were primarily responsible for creating this cost burden.
In its filed comments, GE took the
position that because industrials and other end users within the Commonwealth
did not participate in the writing of take-or-pay contracts, they should not
participate in the dissolving of these contracts. GE cautioned that tampering
with gas prices would cause every end user with the capability to do so to start
burning oil.
Finally, the Commission's staff filed
comments. Its comments observed that all the players in the industry, including
interstate pipelines, local utilities, and end users contributed to take-or-pay
problems. The staff stated that efforts to assess take-or-pay culpability
directly to any of these groups would be highly subjective and difficult to
prove. The staff's comments identified various sources of take-or-pay costs.
For example, a portion of take-or-pay costs are associated with buying-out-or-down
problem contracts and may be a source of prospective benefits. staff further
noted that there were some historical benefits associated with the incurrence
of take-or-pay costs. Staff Comments at 4. Staff noted that significant savings
to end users resulted from spot market purchases. The staff believed that
jurisdictional utilities received no direct benefit from the savings associated
with spot purchases and therefore, it could not support a direct assessment of
take-or-pay costs to these local utilities. Staff Comments at 6.
Staff also characterized take-or-pay costs
as an obstacle to open access transportation and the associated competitive
benefits. Viewed in this light, take-or-pay costs may be considered in the
nature of an access fee for nondiscriminatory transportation. Staff generally
supported recovery of take-or-pay costs through a volumetric surcharge,
provided that the policy was applied with flexibility and sensitivity to each
LDC's competitive situation. Staff acknowledged that a volumetric surcharge
option had certain flaws and recommended that where gas competition with
alternate fuels was rendered impossible after application of the surcharge, the
Commission permit recovery of these costs through an alternative mechanism.
The staff also joined many of the other
commentators and recognized that alternative approaches for allocation of
Pipeline's take-or-pay liability may be appropriate in light of Pipeline's
unique characteristics. These characteristics include Pipeline's readily identifiable
customer population and the significant portion of Pipeline's nongas costs
attributable to take-or-pay costs.
II. THE COMMISSION'S JURISDICTIONAL
AUTHORITY.
As we noted in our July 6th Order for
Notice and Comment, the FERC has properly recognized our authority to
reallocate the fixed surcharges related to take-or-pay and buy-out and buy-down
transactions in Order No. 500:
The Commission [FERC] does not believe
that Nantahala precludes state regulators from designing LDC rates, or, in
appropriate circumstances, from reviewing the prudence of LDCs' purchasing
decisions insofar as they affect take-or-pay costs . . . . Therefore, the
Commission believes state regulators could consider reclassifying take-or-pay
costs billed as a fixed charge as commodity costs and incorporating such costs
into LDC sales or transportation rates, or both, thereby spreading such costs
to the maximum possible extent as well as subjecting them to market forces.
Alternatively, state agencies may wish to consider the option of not
reclassifying fixed take-or-pay charges and instead allocating such charges to
the LDC's customers based on their cumulative purchase deficiencies.
The Commission can exercise its
jurisdiction only within its legitimate sphere, which in this instance involves
establishing cost allocation procedures and rates for recovery by pipelines of
take-or-pay costs from their jurisdictional customers. The development of cost
allocation procedures and rates for the LDCs are matters to be determined by
state regulatory authorities. Order No. 500, III FERC Stats. & Regs., Para.
30,761 at 30,790 (Aug. 14, 1987).
FERC has properly acknowledged our
authority to prescribe the design for the rates and charges of jurisdictional
gas utilities. Section 1(b) of the Natural Gas Act of 1938 ("NGA"),
15 U.S.C. § 717(b) (1982), and the Hinshaw Amendment, 15 U.S.C. § 717 (c),
clearly reserve this area to the regulatory authority of states. The Hinshaw
Amendment granted an exemption from federal regulatory jurisdiction to natural
gas companies if both the receipt and ultimate consumption of gas occur within
a single state, provided the rates, service, and facilities are subject to
regulation by a state commission. A certification by a state commission to the
FERC that the state is exercising such jurisdiction constitutes conclusive
evidence of such regulatory power or jurisdiction. 15 U.S.C. § 717(c).
We have certified to FERC that we regulate
one such pipeline - Commonwealth Gas Pipeline Corporation. LDCs are gas
companies operating in the local distribution of natural gas. Hence the cases
cited by commentators addressing wholesale election power transactions in
interstate commerce are inapposite because those cases, unlike the instant
case, refer to matters directly affecting wholesale rates which are within the
FERC's jurisdiction. Here, the gas companies we regulate are within our
jurisdiction under the provisions of the federal law.
Our authority to design rates for our
jurisdictional gas companies under the Virginia Constitution, statutes, and
case law is unquestioned. As Commonwealth Gas Services, Inc. has observed in
its comments at page 16:
Article IX, Section 2 of the Virginia
Constitution grants to this Commission the power and charges the Commission
with the duty of regulating the rates, charges and services of public utilities
within the Commonwealth. Title 56 of the Code of Virginia, dealing with public
service companies, and particularly Chapter 10 thereof dealing with heat,
light, power, water and other utility companies generally, sets forth the power
and authority of the Commission to consider and determine rates, tolls, charges
and schedules of public utilities to be just and reasonable and to insure that
such rates, tolls, and charges are related to aggregate actual cost incurred by
the public utility in servicing its customers. Such rates also are to provide a
"fair return on the public utility's rate base used to serve those
jurisdictional customers.' § 56-235.2 of the Code of Virginia.
Indeed as the Virginia Supreme Court has
observed:
In fixing rates within the limits of what
is confiscatory to the utility on the one side, and exorbitant as against the
public on the other side . . . there is a reasonably wide area within which the
Commission is empowered to exercise its legislative discretion.
Norfolk v. Chesapeake and Potomac Tel. Co.
of Va., 192 Va. 292,300 (1951).
III. STATEMENT OF POLICY
The Commission obviously enjoys
considerable flexibility under both federal and Virginia statutes to design a
mechanism for recovery of take-or-pay liability. Review of the comments
demonstrates that all of the policy alternatives have associated problems which
must be addressed.
One of the approaches under consideration
was the cumulative deficiency methodology to allocate costs associated with the
take-or-pay liabilities. We are compelled to find that the cumulative
deficiency methodology should be rejected for LDCs. As virtually every LDC that
participated in this proceeding has noted, such a methodology would be
impossible to administer given the diversity of respective LDC customer
populations.
Further, we reject the second policy
alternative-allocation of costs associated with the fixed surcharges to both
firm and interruptible gas commodity costs. This policy could have a deleterious
effect on an LDC's ability to retain interruptible customer loads. As the WGL
Companies' comments have observed, any surcharge affecting the rate charged to
interruptible customers would probably make that rate less attractive vis-a-vis
other fuels. Imposing additional take-or-pay expenses on interruptible
customers would, for example, force the WGL Companies to experience reductions
in margins on their interruptible sales. Reduced margins are directly absorbed
by utilities outside of a rate case. In view of the large percentage of
take-or-pay exposure already included in FERC-approved surcharges, additional
charges in interruptible rates will inappropriately reduce WGL and other
utilities' margins. WGL Comments at 13-14.
The third methodology is, in our opinion,
inappropriate because, as VNG and other commentators have noted, it too will
severely constrain the relative ability of Virginia LDCs to compete with
alternate fuels. To the extent that Virginia utilities must depend on
industrial loads for a large percentage of their operating revenues, both the
financial viability of these companies and the stability of the base gas rates
charged to their firm customers may be jeopardized by the adoption of this
policy alternative.
After review of this record, we are
compelled to find that option 1 is the most appropriate course of action. While
no one option under consideration allocates costs in a completely equitable
manner, this approach has the advantages of being easy to administer and
assuring complete recovery of take-or-pay related costs. In addition, this
approach will not unduly complicate the efforts of Virginia utilities to
compete with alternate fuels.
Additionally, a slightly different tack
must be taken as to the division of take-or-pay costs for LDCs serving multiple
jurisdictions, e.g., WGL. As to these companies, a cumulative deficiency
approach must be used to split the Virginia jurisdictional portion of
take-or-pay costs out of the total company costs. Once these costs have been
identified, then the jurisdictional company may proceed to recover the
identified jurisdictional portion of these costs through its PGA.
Finally, we find that the record supports
treating Commonwealth Gas Pipeline as a unique entity. As virtually every party
to this proceeding has noted, Pipeline is unique by virtue of, among other
things, its limited customer pool and the extremely high percentage of its gas
costs which are take-or-pay related. Pipeline's limited number of customers
allows a more precise measurement of the benefits associated with take-or-pay.
Additionally, Pipeline's unique circumstances provide for a better
identification of the causes of take-or-pay liability. Consequently we find
that Pipeline should be permitted to develop a mechanism for recovery of its
take-or-pay related costs separate and distinct from the policy established
herein for LCDs. Its recovery mechanism should reflect the historic as well as
the prospective benefits derived from gas purchasing practices which have
increased take-or-pay liability. In developing this recovery mechanism, we
encourage Pipeline to work actively with its customers. Should Pipeline and its
customers be unable to reach agreement with regard to a recovery of the
take-or-pay costs in an expeditious manner, this Commission will not hesitate
to prescribe a recovery mechanism.
Accordingly, IT IS ORDERED that all
jurisdictional gas distribution utilities may recover the fixed demand charges
associated with take-or-pay liability and contract reformation through their
purchase gas adjustment clauses. It is further Ordered that Pipeline shall
forthwith file tariffs complying with the principles identified above with
regard to take-or-pay liability. It is finally Ordered that there being nothing
further to be done herein, this matter is hereby dismissed.
Lacy, COMMISSIONER, concurring in part and
dissenting in part:
For the last two years Virginia natural
gas companies and customers have been anticipating the flow-down of costs
associated with the buy-out or buy-down of take-or-pay contracts. During that
time, we have examined the legality, practicality, and fairness of the
available options for recovery of these costs. While no solution is ideal, all
involved do agree that these costs are transitional in nature and must be
resolved before the natural gas industry can realize its market potential.
The cost recovery mechanism chosen by the
majority, automatic recovery through the PGA clause, while the least complex to
administer, does not reflect a fair allocation of cost recovery. I believe
recovering take-or-pay acquisition costs from a broader customer base,
including sales, transportation, and interruptible customers, lessens the
financial burden to any one class of customer and more accurately reflects a
philosophy that responsibility for these costs cannot be assigned to any one
segment of the industry. In my opinion, such a mechanism, combined with the
flexibility for each local gas distribution company to justify some variant or
modification to allow continued competitive operations, while administratively
more complex than the PGA, represents a reasonable and more equitable
resolution to this difficult but transitional situation.
I concur with the majority holding
regarding take-or-pay related costs for Commonwealth Gas Pipeline.
1Regulation
of Natural Gas Pipelines After Partial Well head Decontrol, Docket No.
RM87-34-000, III FERC Stats. & Regs., Paragraph 30,761 (Order No. 500)
(hereafter Order No. 500).
20VAC5-300-80. Order relating to confidential treatment of
Fuel Monitoring Report FM-12. (Repealed.)
By letter dated June 28, 1990, Delmarva
Power and Light Company ("Delmarva") requested that certain
information which Delmarva provides in conjunction with the Commission's fuel
monitoring system be kept confidential and not released to the general public.
On July 18, 1990, Appalachian Power Company requested similar treatment.
Information to support the preparation of "Fuel Monitoring Report 12
(FM12) - Coal and Oil Purchase Summary Report" and several other reports
is filed monthly with the Commission's Division of Economics and Finance to
monitor the fuel expenses incurred by electric utilities in the operation of
generating facilities. The Commission initiated this proceeding when it became
apparent that the fuel monitoring information of all electric utilities
presented similar confidentiality issues.
Section 56-249.3 of the Code of Virginia
requires certain electric utilities to file such information on fuel
transactions and fuel purchases as the Commission deems necessary on a monthly
basis. It is pursuant to this statute that utilities file the information to
support the preparation of Report FM12 and several additional reports. Report
FM12 contains a very specific breakdown of information related to the utilities'
purchases of coal and oil. Section 56-249.3 of the Code of Virginia provides
that the information required from utilities may include the supplier of the
fossil fuel; the cost in cents per MBTU, with a notation of whether the fuel
was contracted for, purchased on the spot market, or purchased from an
affiliate of the electric utility; total demurrage charges incurred at each
generating plant; total cost of transportation incurred at each generating
plant; and the average cost of the fossil fuel in cents per MBTU's consumed at
each plant with and without handling charges. Section 56-249.4 of the Code of
Virginia provides that any information filed in accordance with § 56-249.3 of
the Code of Virginia shall be open to the public. Although the Commission has
wide discretion to determine the information to be filed under § 56-249.3, we
have no discretion under § 56-249.4 to withhold some of the information from
public disclosure.
Nevertheless, the Commission finds that
the confidentiality concerns of the electric utilities are well-founded in one
respect. Under § 56-249.3 of the Code of Virginia we have heretofore required
separate reporting of both the delivered price of fossil fuel and the cost of
its transportation to various utility facilities. This level of detail is not
necessary for the public reports prepared under § 56-249.3, in our view. In the
future, for purposes of § 56-249.3, utilities may report total delivered fossil
fuel prices without separate reporting of transportation costs. For regulatory
monitoring purposes, the staff may require the utilities to continue to provide
detailed fossil fuel purchase information outside of the context of § 56-249.3
and under an appropriate agreement of confidentiality.
Our decision here should not be interpreted
to permit utility companies to refuse disclosure to our staff of any
information which staff deems necessary to accomplish its official duties. Nor
should it be read as a defense to discovery by any party to a commission
proceeding, subject to appropriate protective orders if necessary. Staff review
and the scrutiny of other parties in fuel factor and other Commission
proceedings should be sufficient to protect the public interest in reasonable
utility fuel purchases. Accordingly,
IT IS ORDERED:
1. That electric utility companies filing information under §
56-249.3 of the Code of Virginia may report fuel purchase costs on the basis of
total delivered prices;
2. That all information reported by electric utility companies
pursuant to § 56-249.3 of the Code of Virginia shall continue to be made public
by the Commission pursuant to § 56-249.4 of the Code of Virginia; and
3. That, there being nothing further to come before the Commission
in this proceeding, Case Number PUE900046 shall be closed and the papers therein
placed in the Commission's files for ended causes.
20VAC5-300-100. Standards for fuel cost projections of
electric utilities. (Repealed.)
The 1989 Session of the General Assembly
adopted Senate Joint Resolution No. 156 ("Resolution") requesting the
State Corporation Commission to establish standards for evaluating the
reasonableness of the fuel cost projections of electric utilities. The Resolution
stated that "such standards need to be established in order to ensure that
payments for power purchased by electric utilities from cogenerators are fair,
reasonable, and appropriate." Pursuant to that Resolution, the Commission,
by an order dated January 10, 1990, directed its staff to complete an
investigation and submit its findings and recommendations in a report. On
February 15, 1990, staff submitted its Report on the Development of Standards
for Fuel Cost Projections ("Staff Report").
By Order dated March 16, 1990, the
Commission directed its Division of Energy Regulation to provide notice of the
proposed standards contained in the Staff Report and invited interested persons
to comment and to request a hearing. Pursuant to that March 16, 1990, Order,
the Commission received comments from CRSS Capital, Inc.; Chesapeake
Corporation, Stone Container Corporation, and Westvaco Corporation
("Industrial Protestants"); and Delmarva Power
("Delmarva").
Fuel cost projections have several
interrelated applications and, accordingly, the accuracy of those projections
is very important. First, an electric utility must make fuel cost projections
to facilitate optimal resource planning. The more accurate the fuel cost
projections, the better the utility can anticipate and plan for its future
needs.
As emphasized in the Resolution, fuel cost
projections are also essential to ensure payments for power purchased from
cogenerators and small power producers are fair and reasonable.
Administratively determined payments to such qualifying facilities are based
upon an electric utility's avoided costs, which are necessarily calculated by
projecting the utility's system costs, but for the purchases from the
qualifying facilities. The assumptions underlying that calculation clearly must
include fuel cost projections. Again, to ensure payments that are fair to the
qualifying facility and to the ratepayer, those projections must be as accurate
as possible.
Finally, fuel cost projections must be
made to develop the fuel factor which an electric utility adds to its base
rates for all electricity sold. Each fuel factor is designed to recover the
fuel costs the utility expects to incur during the subsequent twelve months. It
also includes a correction factor designed to correct any over or under
recovery of prior period fuel expenses. Although the fuel factor includes a
true-up mechanism, it is still important for the utility to base the factor on
accurate fuel cost projections to minimize extreme fluctuations or variances in
customers' bills.
Staff recommends, and we agree, that
standards for fuel cost projections should be broad and flexible. Such a
framework will allow the standards to be readily applied to each individual
utility in differing circumstances. General parameters, however, must be
established.
Staff recommends the following minimum
standards for fuel cost projections:
1. A sophisticated "state-of-the-art" production costing
model should be utilized for projecting fuel expenses.
2. Key input data and assumptions should reflect historic data.
Any significant deviation from historic trends should be adequately explained
and evaluated for reasonableness.
3. Key input data such as load forecasts, generating unit
characteristics, fuel data, and system parameters should be developed in the
same relative time frame and reflect consistent assumptions.
4. Demand forecasts should be current and reflect economic growth,
normal weather, the price of electricity, elasticity assumptions, appliance
saturations, income and population changes in the utility's service area. They
should also reflect projections of energy, peak demand and the effects of
demand-side options.
5. Expected fuel prices should reflect historic fuel costs
adjusted for any known dynamics of the projection: i.e., labor contracts,
expected operation of the spot market, current fuel contracts, the world fuel
market, inventory levels and fuel availabilities, purchasing volumes, coal
severance taxes, etc.
6. Unit operations should consider planned maintenance, forced
outages, expected dispatch levels, historical performance levels, seasonal
capabilities, as well as ongoing enhancements or unit deterioration.
7. Dispatch orders should reflect such variables as system
economics, unit availabilities, minimum operating levels, heat rates, and terms
and conditions of purchased power contracts.
8. Purchase power levels should consider need, system economics,
power availability and transmission constraints.
9. Projections supporting the development of cogeneration rates
should include a comparison of key input data and assumptions from the last
fuel projection filed with the Commission. Major changes should be adequately
explained.
20VAC5-317-40. Initial implementation of standby rates. (Repealed.)
On or before April 1, 2010, each utility
shall submit to the State Corporation Commission (commission) a plan setting
forth the utility's plan for compliance with this chapter. A utility may submit
its existing standby provisions as its proposed plan for compliance with this
chapter. Thereafter, following notice and an opportunity for hearing, the
commission will determine whether a utility's plan complies with this chapter.
20VAC5-320-120. Filing schedule. (Repealed.)
Each incumbent electric utility required
to obtain commission authorization for the transfer of its transmission assets
to an RTE shall file the application required by 20VAC5-320-90 with the Clerk
of the Commission not later than October 16, 2000.
VA.R. Doc. No. R20-6264; Filed April 13, 2020, 9:49 a.m.